Section: Social Complexity / Forms of money
Variable: Paper Currency (All coded records)
Paper currency or another kind of fiat money. Note that this only refers to indigenously produced paper currency. Code absent if colonial money is used.  
Paper Currency
#  Polity  Coded Value Tags Year(s) Edit Desc
1 Mossi unknown Suspected 1100 CE 1750 CE
The following information strictly applies to the period immediately preceding colonisation--however, given global trends in the history of currency, it seems very unlikely for paper currency to have existed in this region prior to the 18th century. "Cowries and cotton bands were used as currency." [1]

[1]: (Englebert 2018: 15) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/52JWRCUI/collection.


2 Russian Empire, Romanov Dynasty I absent Confident 1615 CE 1769 CE
The first instance of paper currency in Russia was introduced during the reign of Peter the Great. The Assignation Ruble was the first paper currency of the Russian Empire, introduced in 1769. [1]

[1]: Pick, Albert. Standard Catalog of World Paper Money. 2: General Issues: 1368-1960 / George S. Cuhaj, Editor. Edited by George S. Cuhaj. 13. ed. Iola, Wisc: Krause, 2010. Zotero link: 4QMQVGF7


3 Portuguese Empire - Early Modern absent Confident 1640 CE 1796 CE
-
4 French Kingdom - Late Bourbon present Confident Expert 1700 CE 1720 CE
Initiative of Desmarets 1700s CE which failed then Law’s System which crashed 1720 CE. [1] [2]

“The history of paper money in France is usually associated with the figure of John Law who, with the support of the Regent, Philippe, duc d’Orléans, between 1716 and 1720, carried out financial experiments to sustain the French currency on the international money market, boost economic activity and restructure the war debt accumulated in the course of Louis XIV’s wars. However, as John Law acknowledged, France had already used paper money, and the dire memory of this earlier monetary experience featured high among the arguments of those, in government, who initially opposed the Scot’s proposal to establish a bank and issue notes. ‘The public’, John Law observed in December 1715, ‘is against the bank because of the billets de monnoye [mint bills], of the caisse des emprunts, etc., which have brought great prejudice to commerce and individuals’ (Harsin 1934, II, p. 274).

“That first introduction of fiat money in the kingdom took place on the initiative of Michel Chamillart (1652-1721) who held both the posts of contrôleur général des finances (1699- 1708) and secrétaire d’État de la guerre (1701-1709). The decision to issue paper money as legal tender is certainly Chamillart’s most original and dramatic (if largely forgotten) contribution to the history of France, as it led to the first experience of fiat money inflation.” [3]

[1]: (Briggs 1998, 151)

[2]: (Ladurie 1991, 290)

[3]: (Felix 2018: 43) Felix, J. 2018. ‘The most difficult financial matter that has ever presented itself’: paper money and the financing of warfare under Louis XIV. Financial History Review 25(1): 43-70. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/URTP9U5H/library


5 Spanish Empire II absent Confident Expert 1716 CE 1814 CE
“The strongbox of the new bank was kept in the sacristy of the cathedral, and when in 1628 the clergy protested against keeping it so close to the relics of the saints it was shifted just a short distance away to a special chamber upstairs. Neither it nor its equivalent of the same name in Barcelona were supposed to do anything with the treasure other than keep it under lock and key, issuing the depositor with an albarà—a certificate of his holding. In time the albarans began to circulate as a kind of currency, transferring deposits from one citizen to another to whom he owed money. But this nascent paper currency was largely aborted in the seventeenth century, as the Taula began to spend more money than it had in reserve. The successive bankruptcies of 1614, 1634 and 1649 in Valencia led to the conversion of the promissory notes (the albarans) into non-redeemable bonds on the municipal treasury.”(Casey 2002: 70) Casey, James. 2002. Early Modern Spain: A Social History. New York: Routledge. https://www.zotero.org/groups/seshat_databank/items/itemKey/2SNTRSWT
6 Mossi absent Confident 1751 CE 1897 CE
The following information strictly applies to the period immediately preceding colonisation--however, given global trends in the history of currency, it seems very unlikely for paper currency to have existed in this region prior to the 18th century. "Cowries and cotton bands were used as currency." [1]

[1]: (Englebert 2018: 15) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/52JWRCUI/collection.


7 Russian Empire, Romanov Dynasty I present Confident 1769 CE 1775 CE
-
8 Rattanakosin absent Confident Expert 1782 CE 1862 CE
"Machine-minted coins and printed paper money appeared in 1862, when the imported cowries were officially taken out of circulation." [1]

[1]: (Van Dongen, no publication year, p. 10)


9 Portuguese Empire - Early Modern present Confident 1797 CE 1806 CE
-
10 Rattanakosin present Confident Expert 1862 CE 1873 CE
"Machine-minted coins and printed paper money appeared in 1862, when the imported cowries were officially taken out of circulation." [1]

[1]: (Van Dongen, no publication year, p. 10)


11 Austria - Habsburg Dynasty II present Confident 1867 CE 1918 CE
“Gulden banknotes issued by the Bank were printed in German on one side, Hungarian (as Forints) on the other.” [1] “By 1918 tax and non-tax income covered less than 20% of current war expenditures. The war was financed in two main ways: war loans in the form of eight public bond drives covered 53%, and direct credits (with newly printed money) provided via the Austro-Hungarian National Bank and other bank consortia financed another 42% of war costs, imposing a huge burden of hyperinflation on the postwar economy.” [2]

[1]: (Boyer 2022: 176, footnote) Boyer, John W. 2022. Austria, 1867–1955. Oxford: Oxford University Press. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/CG3P4KKD

[2]: (Boyer 2022: 536) Boyer, John W. 2022. Austria, 1867–1955. Oxford: Oxford University Press. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/CG3P4KKD


12 Soviet Union present Confident Expert 1923 CE 1991 CE
The origins of the Russian ruble as a designation of silver weight can be traced to the 13th century. In 1704 Tsar Peter I (the Great) introduced the first regular minting of the ruble in silver. During the 18th century it was debased, and, after the middle of the 19th century, the rapidly depreciating paper money predominated in Russia’s circulation. In 1897 a gold ruble was substituted for the silver one, marking the change to a gold standard. Early in World War I, gold coins disappeared from circulation, and notes became inconvertible. During the period of the Russian Revolution and civil war, an inflation of astronomical dimensions made the ruble virtually worthless. A reform carried out during 1922–23 reestablished an orderly monetary system. The chervonets was introduced as the standard unit and the basis of the state bank’s note issue; the chervonets ruble, corresponding to one-tenth of a chervonets, was made a unit of reckoning. The ruble remained a term of denomination for treasury notes and silver coins. In the post-World War II reform of 1947, the chervonets was abandoned as the monetary standard and the ruble restored. [1]

[1]: “Ruble | Russian Currency, Exchange Rate, History & Value Definition | Britannica Money.” Accessed November 26, 2023. https://www.britannica.com/money/ruble. Zotero link: 2HBX67H7


13 Kievan Rus absent Confident -
-
14 Bito Dynasty absent Confident -
-
15 Cwezi Dynasty absent Inferred -
-
16 Early Tana 2 absent Inferred -
-
17 Avar Khaganate absent Confident -
-
18 Axum II absent Confident -
-
19 Axum III absent Confident -
-
20 Bagan absent Inferred -
-
21 Banu Ghaniya absent Confident -
-
22 Bulgaria - Early absent Confident -
-
23 Bulgaria - Middle absent Confident -
-
24 Chandela Kingdom absent Confident -
-
25 Chauhana Dynasty absent Confident -
-
26 Chaulukya Dynasty absent Confident -
-
27 Chu Kingdom - Spring and Autumn Period absent Confident -
-
28 Chu Kingdom - Warring States Period absent Inferred -
-
29 Crimean Khanate unknown Suspected -
-
30 Early Greater Coclé absent Inferred -
-
31 Early Nyoro absent Inferred -
-
32 Early Tana 2 absent Inferred -
-
33 Idrisids absent Confident -
-
34 Jayarid Khanate absent Confident -
-
35 Kakatiya Dynasty absent Confident -
-
36 Kamarupa Kingdom absent Confident -
-
37 Kangju absent Confident -
-
38 Kazan Khanate unknown Suspected -
-
39 Kingdom of Congo absent Confident -
-
40 Kingdom of Georgia II absent Inferred -
-
41 Kingdom of Sicily - Hohenstaufen and Angevin dynasties absent Confident -
-
42 Ghur Principality unknown Suspected Expert -
-
43 Carolingian Empire I absent Confident Expert -
“The history of paper money in France is usually associated with the figure of John Law who, with the support of the Regent, Philippe, duc d’Orléans, between 1716 and 1720, carried out financial experiments to sustain the French currency on the international money market, boost economic activity and restructure the war debt accumulated in the course of Louis XIV’s wars. However, as John Law acknowledged, France had already used paper money, and the dire memory of this earlier monetary experience featured high among the arguments of those, in government, who initially opposed the Scot’s proposal to establish a bank and issue notes. ‘The public’, John Law observed in December 1715, ‘is against the bank because of the billets de monnoye [mint bills], of the caisse des emprunts, etc., which have brought great prejudice to commerce and individuals’ (Harsin 1934, II, p. 274).

“That first introduction of fiat money in the kingdom took place on the initiative of Michel Chamillart (1652-1721) who held both the posts of contrôleur général des finances (1699- 1708) and secrétaire d’État de la guerre (1701-1709). The decision to issue paper money as legal tender is certainly Chamillart’s most original and dramatic (if largely forgotten) contribution to the history of France, as it led to the first experience of fiat money inflation.” [1]

[1]: (Felix 2018: 43) Felix, J. 2018. ‘The most difficult financial matter that has ever presented itself’: paper money and the financing of warfare under Louis XIV. Financial History Review 25(1): 43-70. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/URTP9U5H/library


44 Gurjar-Pratihara Dynasty absent Confident Expert -
-
45 Wei Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
"The Song dynasty introduced paper money in 1024 because China did not have enough silver or copper for its growing commercial economy." [1]

[1]: (Headrick 2009, 85)


46 La Mula-Sarigua absent Inferred -
-
47 Late Greater Coclé absent Inferred -
-
48 Later Qin Kingdom absent Inferred -
-
49 Later Yan Kingdom absent Inferred -
-
50 Leon & Castille absent Inferred -
-
51 Makuria Kingdom I absent Confident -
-
52 Makuria Kingdom II absent Confident -
-
53 Makuria Kingdom III absent Confident -
-
54 Malacca Sultanate unknown Suspected -
-
55 Malacca Sultanate absent Confident -
-
56 Maukhari Dynasty absent Confident -
-
57 Mauretania absent Confident -
-
58 Middle Greater Coclé absent Inferred -
-
59 Monte Alban V Early Postclassic absent Confident -
-
60 Monte Alban V Late Postclassic absent Confident -
-
61 Numidia absent Confident -
-
62 Ottoman Empire Late Period absent Inferred -
-
63 Paramara Dynasty absent Confident -
-
64 Russian Principate absent Confident -
-
65 Songhai Empire absent Confident -
-
66 Sukhotai absent Inferred -
-
67 Tahert absent Confident -
-
68 Third Scythian Kingdom absent Confident -
-
69 Tlemcen absent Inferred -
-
70 Wattasid absent Confident -
-
71 Yadava Dynasty absent Confident -
-
72 Zagwe absent Inferred -
-
73 Zirids absent Confident -
-
74 Neolithic Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
75 New Palace Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
76 Old Palace Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
77 Republic of Venice III absent Inferred Expert -
Paper currency not mentioned in histories/descriptions of the Venetian currency system, which appears to be relatively well studied. For example:

"From its origins in the early Middle Ages,Venice relied on different coins for different monetary roles. As the medieval centuries progressed, the Venetian state introduced separate denominations with distinctive appearances in terms of size, color, and imagery to fill the various monetary niches. The different metals used for these issues, and divergent rates of seignorage applied to their minting, resulted in inequities in the coinages used by different sectors of the economy. Venetian authorities made no mention of the effects of monetary changes on various social groups, but they could not have been ignorant of the disparities in outcome." [1]

[1]: (Stahl 2007, 195) Stahl, A. 2007. Coins for Trade and for Wages: The Development of Coinage Systems in Medieval Venice. In Lucassen, J. (ed) Wages and currency. Global comparisons from antiquity to the twentieth century pp. 193-209. Peter Lang. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/ZWWBS2BC/library


78 Proto-Carolingian absent Inferred Expert -
-
79 Papal States - Renaissance Period absent Confident Expert -
-
80 Exarchate of Ravenna absent Confident Expert -
-
81 Republic of Venice IV absent Inferred Expert -
Paper currency not mentioned in histories/descriptions of the Venetian currency system, which appears to be relatively well studied. For example:

"From its origins in the early Middle Ages,Venice relied on different coins for different monetary roles. As the medieval centuries progressed, the Venetian state introduced separate denominations with distinctive appearances in terms of size, color, and imagery to fill the various monetary niches. The different metals used for these issues, and divergent rates of seignorage applied to their minting, resulted in inequities in the coinages used by different sectors of the economy. Venetian authorities made no mention of the effects of monetary changes on various social groups, but they could not have been ignorant of the disparities in outcome." [1]

[1]: (Stahl 2007, 195) Stahl, A. 2007. Coins for Trade and for Wages: The Development of Coinage Systems in Medieval Venice. In Lucassen, J. (ed) Wages and currency. Global comparisons from antiquity to the twentieth century pp. 193-209. Peter Lang. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/ZWWBS2BC/library


82 Egypt - Inter-Occupation Period absent Inferred Expert -
-
83 Egypt - Mamluk Sultanate I absent Confident Expert -
-
84 Egypt - Mamluk Sultanate III absent Confident Expert -
-
85 Japan - Middle Jomon absent Inferred Expert -
Paper currency first introduced in the 1600s [1] .

[1]: (Snodgrass 2003, 254)


86 Egypt - Mamluk Sultanate II absent Confident Expert -
-
87 Shuar - Colonial absent Confident Expert -
-
88 Ayyubid Sultanate absent Inferred Expert -
-
89 Badarian absent Inferred Expert -
-
90 Egypt - Dynasty I absent Inferred Expert -
-
91 Egypt - Dynasty II absent Inferred Expert -
-
92 Greco-Bactrian Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
-
93 Kidarite Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
94 Kushan Empire absent Confident Expert -
-
95 Tocharians absent Confident Expert -
-
96 Hmong - Late Qing absent Confident Expert -
-
97 Northern Wei absent Confident Expert -
-
98 Sui Dynasty absent Inferred Expert -
-
99 Tang Dynasty II absent Inferred Expert -
-
100 Early Wei Dynasty absent Inferred Expert -
-
101 Neguanje unknown Suspected Expert -
-
102 Tairona unknown Suspected Expert -
-
103 Antebellum US Transitional (Absent -> Present) Confident -
Paper currency in the form of Treasury Notes, began to be issued in order to fund the War of 1812. [1]

[1]: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/United_States_dollar


104 Austria - Habsburg Dynasty II Transitional (Absent -> Present) Confident -
“By 1795 the government was printing paper money to cover the added costs of war, and by 1797—as a result of a panic caused by fears that Napoleon would take Vienna— silver was completely withdrawn from circulation, and state employees and state creditors had to accept paper bills as their payment.” [1]

[1]: (Judson 2016: 90) Judson, Pieter M. 2016. The Habsburg Empire: A New History. Cambridge, USA; London, England: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/BN5TQZBW


105 Russian Empire, Romanov Dynasty II present Confident Expert -
-
106 Egypt - Middle Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
-
107 Naqada I absent Inferred Expert -
-
108 Naqada II absent Inferred Expert -
-
109 Egypt - Dynasty 0 absent Inferred Expert -
-
110 Egypt - New Kingdom Ramesside Period absent Confident Expert -
-
111 Egypt - New Kingdom Thutmosid Period absent Confident Expert -
-
112 Egypt - Classic Old Kingdom absent Inferred Expert -
-
113 Egypt - Late Old Kingdom absent Inferred Expert -
-
114 Ptolemaic Kingdom I absent Confident Expert -
-
115 Ptolemaic Kingdom II absent Confident Expert -
-
116 Egypt - Period of the Regions absent Inferred Expert -
-
117 Egypt - Saite Period absent Confident Expert -
-
118 Egypt - Thebes-Hyksos Period absent Confident Expert -
-
119 Egypt - Thebes-Libyan Period absent Inferred Expert -
-
120 Egypt - Tulunid-Ikhshidid Period absent Inferred Expert -
-
121 Axum I absent Confident Expert -
-
122 Chuuk - Early Truk absent Confident Expert -
-
123 Beaker Culture unknown Suspected Expert -
-
124 French Kingdom - Early Bourbon unknown Suspected Expert -
-
125 Proto-French Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
126 French Kingdom - Late Capetian absent Inferred Expert -
-
127 Carolingian Empire II absent Inferred Expert -
-
128 Hallstatt A-B1 unknown Suspected Expert -
-
129 Hallstatt B2-3 unknown Suspected Expert -
-
130 Hallstatt C unknown Suspected Expert -
-
131 Hallstatt D unknown Suspected Expert -
-
132 Early Merovingian unknown Suspected Expert -
-
133 Middle Merovingian unknown Suspected Expert -
-
134 La Tene A-B1 unknown Suspected Expert -
-
135 La Tene B2-C1 unknown Suspected Expert -
-
136 La Tene C2-D absent Confident Expert -
-
137 French Kingdom - Late Valois unknown Suspected Expert -
-
138 Akan - Pre-Ashanti absent Confident Expert -
-
139 Archaic Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
140 Classical Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
141 The Emirate of Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
142 Final Postpalatial Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
143 Geometric Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
144 Monopalatial Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
145 Erligang absent Confident Expert -
Paper did not exist at this time. It has been suggested that cowrie shells were used as a currency. [1]

[1]: (Yuan 2013, 336-337)


146 Erlitou absent Confident Expert -
Paper did not exist at this time.
147 Hmong - Early Chinese absent Confident Expert -
(this position codes only for indigenously produced currency) Chinese currency was used where markets and cash were accessible: ’Trade. - The Miao people do not know how to trade. Formerly, the Chinese brought salt and cloth into the Miao villages to exchange for their local products, but there were many dishonest traders, who cheated the Miao, giving rise to much confusion at times. Later the Chinese were officially prohibited from entering Miao villages to trade, but certain places were designated for sitting up markets, to be used once every five days, six times a month. The best-known markets among the Miao are the Te-sheng-ying, Kan-tzu-p’ing, Ya-pao-chai, Ya-la-ying, and Hsin-chai (Illus. 40) of Feng-huang; the Ta-hsin-chai of Kan-ch’eng; and the Wei-ch’eng, Lung-t’an, and Ma-li-ch’ang of Yung-sui. The important articles of trade are salt, cloth, animals, /Illus. 39, p. 73/ /Illus. 40 appears here/ and grains. Formerly, in trade between the Chinese and the Miao four small bowls were equal to one sheng. For cloth one measure between two hands was considered four ch’ih. The price of cattle and horses are set by the number of fists, regardless of age. The method of measurement by fist is like this. They take a bamboo splint and wind it around the fore ribs of the cow to set its girth, and then they measure the bamboo splint with their fists. A water buffalo which measures 16 fists is big, and a common yellow cow which measures 13 fists is large. The operation is called “fisting a cow.” In the case of horses age does come into consideration. They measure a horse from the ground to the saddle place by comparing it with a wooden rod. A 13-fist high one is big. A horse with few teeth but of many fists fetches a higher price, and the reverse fetches a lower price. This operation is called “comparing horses.” In recent times, in the sale of rice, cloth, and other articles, they have adopted the Chinese standards of weight and measurement, but “fisting cows” and “comparing horses” are sometimes still done.’ [1] ’There are localities where the Ch’uan Miao barter a great deal because of the shortage of money, the differences being paid in cash. This is more common in northern Yunnan than in Szechwan where market-places and towns are more accessible. The Ch’uan Miao sell cattle, goats, sheep, horses, pigs, chickens, corn, rice, eggs and vegetables and purchase salt. cloth, silver ornaments, pottery and implements and tools made of iron.’ [2] Cash gifts were also part of marriage negotiations: ’A considerable time is allowed to elapse between engagement and marriage. Before the wedding ceremony the boy’s parents select another lucky day to make a formal call upon the girl’s family in company with five to eight relatives to deliver cash and other gifts. This is called “sung p’ing-chin” /sending betrothal money/ or "tsou k’ê /going as guests/. The cash present varies from $30 or $50 up to $400 or $500, depending upon the financial ability of the boy’s family. The dowry of the girl is also proportional to the amount of cash. Other gifts include glutinous rice, (rich families giving as many as one or two piculs /a picul is 100 catties or 133.3 1 bs/), puffed rice /candies/, cakes, brown sugar, a silver necklace, and one or two fat pigs. The gifts are placed on table scaffoldings, each carried by two men. The presents of rich families can be quite lavish and sometimes amount to as many as a dozen tables. [...] The head of the groom’s family then picks up the cash and the silver necklace both wrapped in a piece of red paper and places them on the rice. Next he burns incense and lights candles to worship the ancestors. After a few minutes the four representatives at the table each pick up a bowl of wine and empties it in one gulp. These then become the witnesses who are required to testify in the event of marital complications or divorce. At that time, if the bride’s family considers the cash gift as not large enough to match the dowry, they may ask their representatives to refrain from drinking the wine to indicate dissatisfaction.’ [3]

[1]: Ling, Shun-sheng, Yifu Ruey, and Lien-en Tsao 1947. “Report On An Investigation Of The Miao Of Western Hunan”, 103

[2]: Graham, David Crockett 1937. “Customs Of The Ch’Uan Miao", 24

[3]: Che-lin, Wu, Chen Kuo-chün, and Lien-en Tsao 1942. “Studies Of Miao-I Societies In Kweichow”, 44


148 Jin absent Confident Expert -
Would not be invented for another couple thousand years.
149 Longshan absent Confident Expert -
Paper did not exist at this time.
150 Jin Dynasty present Inferred Expert -
As Northern Song.
151 Late Shang absent Confident Expert -
Paper did not exist at this time. Cowrie shells used at the time [1] Jade [2] .

[1]: (Kerr 2013, 20)

[2]: (Peers 2011, 278)


152 Western Han Empire present Inferred Expert -
Emperor Wu experimented with "paper" money. Used the hide of a rare white deer that only he possessed. 1 note to 400,000 copper coins. Money raising exercise. [1]

[1]: (Kerr 2013, 36)


153 Yangshao absent Confident Expert -
Paper did not exist at this time.
154 Atlantic Complex unknown Suspected Expert -
No information found in sources so far.
155 Ashanti Empire absent Confident Expert -
According to SCCS variable 17 ’Money (Media of Exchange) and Credit’ ’Tokens of conventional value as media of exchange’ were used, not ’No media of exchange or money’ or ’Domestically used articles as media of exchange’ or ’Foreign coinage or paper coinage’, or ’Indigenous coinage or paper currency’.
156 Postpalatial Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
157 Prepalatial Crete absent Confident Expert -
-
158 Iban - Pre-Brooke absent Confident Expert -
-
159 Kalingga Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
160 Mataram Sultanate unknown Suspected Expert -
-
161 Canaan absent Confident Expert -
-
162 Yehuda absent Confident Expert -
-
163 Yisrael absent Confident Expert -
-
164 Chalukyas of Badami unknown Suspected Expert -
-
165 Chalukyas of Kalyani unknown Suspected Expert -
-
166 Deccan - Iron Age unknown Suspected Expert -
-
167 Deccan - Neolithic absent Inferred Expert -
-
168 Hoysala Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
169 Kadamba Empire unknown Suspected Expert -
-
170 Kampili Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
171 Mughal Empire absent Inferred Expert -
-
172 Satavahana Empire unknown Suspected Expert -
-
173 Vakataka Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
174 Vijayanagara Empire unknown Suspected Expert -
-
175 Abbasid Caliphate I absent Confident Expert -
-
176 Abbasid Caliphate II absent Confident Expert -
-
177 Isin-Larsa absent Confident Expert -
-
178 Neo-Assyrian Empire absent Confident Expert -
-
179 Achaemenid Empire absent Confident Expert -
-
180 Ak Koyunlu unknown Suspected Expert -
-
181 Susiana - Muhammad Jaffar absent Confident Expert -
-
182 Elam - Awan Dynasty I unknown Suspected Expert -
-
183 Buyid Confederation unknown Suspected Expert -
-
184 Elymais II absent Confident Expert -
-
185 Formative Period unknown Suspected Expert -
-
186 Susiana A absent Confident Expert -
-
187 Susiana B unknown Suspected Expert -
-
188 Susiana - Late Ubaid unknown Suspected Expert -
-
189 Susiana - Early Ubaid unknown Suspected Expert -
-
190 Elam - Kidinuid Period absent Confident Expert -
-
191 Elam - Igihalkid Period absent Confident Expert -
-
192 Elam - Shutrukid Period absent Confident Expert -
-
193 Elam I absent Confident Expert -
-
194 Elam II absent Confident Expert -
-
195 Elam III absent Confident Expert -
-
196 Parthian Empire I absent Confident Expert -
-
197 Parthian Empire II absent Confident Expert -
-
198 Pre-Ceramic Period unknown Suspected Expert -
-
199 Sasanid Empire I absent Confident Expert -
-
200 Sasanid Empire II absent Confident Expert -
-
201 Seleucids unknown Suspected Expert -
-
202 Elam - Early Sukkalmah absent Confident Expert -
-
203 Susa I unknown Suspected Expert -
-
204 Susa II unknown Suspected Expert -
-
205 Susa III unknown Suspected Expert -
-
206 Ostrogothic Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
-
207 Rome - Republic of St Peter II absent Confident Expert -
-
208 Papal States - High Medieval Period absent Confident Expert -
-
209 Iban - Brooke Raj and Colonial present Confident Expert -
According to SCCS variable 17 ’Money (Media of Exchange) and Credit’, ’No media of exchange or money’ or ’Domestically used articles as media of exchange’ or ’Tokens of conventional value as media of exchange’ or ’Foreign coinage or paper coinage’, or ’Indigenous coinage or paper currency’. The trade economy was monetized during the Brooke Raj and colonial periods, with the associated introduction of cash crops: ‘Another factor that appears to have been favourably regarded by the Iban, as well as other indigenous groups, was the opportunities that trade offered in acquiring a reserve capital and various prestige items. Trade, which was part of the rationale for pacification, was concerned in Iban areas with jungle produce like rattan and wild rubber which were shipped down-river in return for a counter-stream of items like salt, steel, iron, brass wire and gongs, crockery ware and the highly valued sacred jars of Chinese origin. After this trade had reached some bulk in the 1870’s and until the introduction of cultivated rubber it provided around thirty per cent of the state’s total exports. Rubber, which started to be grown in considerable quantities in the first decade of this century, became the most important of the small-holder cash-crops for the indigenous peoples. To begin with it was planted by many Iban communities in both the Second and the Third Division, but around the middle or late 1920’s non-Christian communities began cutting down their rubber trees. […] Prior to rubber, another cash-crop, coffee, had been grown with some success in the Second Division, notably amongst the Saribas Iban. The overproduction that completely upset the world market in 1897 and the drastic fall in prices, however, put an abrupt end to this endeavour.’ [1] ’With the rubber boom of 1950 this balance was completely disturbed. In September, 1950 (one year after the period we have just been discussing), Chinese traders were travelling all the rivers of the Baleh region in search of Iban rubber, and the price offered at Rumah Nyala was $1.50 per kati. Accepting an average daily output per worker of 5 katis, in September, 1950, the production of rubber had become a pursuit at least three times more profitable than the production of padi. Hulled rice ( brau ) had risen in price to about $2 per gantang. Under these conditions it is difficult to understand, if one is thinking purely in terms of immediate profit and loss, why farming was not abandoned in favour of full-time rubber production. In the Saribas District of the Second Division, indeed, there was a marked tendency in this direction. At Gansurai, a Dayak long-house on the banks of the Layar River, for example, 6 of the 19 bilek families did not grow any padi during the 1950-51 season, and were relying entirely on imported rice which they were able to purchase with money obtained from the sale of rubber. This was no great difficulty. One of the bilek families of Gansurai, employed 11 Malays on a share-cropping basis, and in April, 1951, with rubber at $1.15 per kati, the monthly income of this family was about $1,400.’ [2]

[1]: Wagner, Ulla 1972. “Colonialism And Iban Warfare”, 41

[2]: Freeman, Derek 1955. “Iban Agriculture: A Report On The Shifting Cultivation Of Hill Rice By The Iban Of Sarawak”, 106


210 Medang Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: (Miksic 1988, 3)


211 Magadha - Maurya Empire absent Confident Expert -
Only coins being issued by the state mints. [1]

[1]: Allchin, F. Raymond. The Archaeology of Early Historic South Asia: The Emergence of Cities and States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995. pp. 218-221.


212 Rashtrakuta Empire absent Inferred Expert -
Inferred from the fact that contemporary sources describe silver coins, but not paper currency [1]

[1]: Jayashri Mishra, Social and Economic Conditions Under the Imperial Rashtrakutas (1992), p. 20


213 Akkadian Empire absent Confident Expert -
Monetary system did not existed in the Akkadian Empire Period.
214 Early Dynastic absent Confident Expert -
Monetary system did not exist in the Early Dynastic Period.
215 Ubaid absent Confident Expert -
Monetary system did not exist in the Ubaid.
216 Ur - Dynasty III absent Confident Expert -
Monetary system did not exist in the Ur III polity.
217 Uruk absent Confident Expert -
Monetary system did not exist in the Uruk polity.
218 Safavid Empire unknown Suspected Expert -
No data.
219 Seljuk Sultanate absent Inferred Expert -
Not mentioned in sources so far consulted.
220 Elam - Shimashki Period absent Inferred Expert -
Monetary system did not exist in the Shimashki’s polity
221 Icelandic Commonwealth absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: Axel Kristissen; Arni D Juliusson pers. comm. 2017


222 Latium - Bronze Age absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
223 Latium - Copper Age absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
224 Latium - Iron Age absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
225 Western Roman Empire - Late Antiquity absent Confident Expert -
-
226 Republic of St Peter I absent Confident Expert -
-
227 Asuka absent Confident Expert -
-
228 Japan - Azuchi-Momoyama absent Confident Expert -
-
229 Nara Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
-
230 Western Turk Khaganate unknown Suspected Expert -
-
231 Andronovo absent Confident Expert -
-
232 Phoenician Empire absent Confident Expert -
-
233 Saadi Sultanate unknown Suspected Expert -
-
234 Bamana kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
235 Jenne-jeno I unknown Suspected Expert -
-
236 Jenne-jeno II unknown Suspected Expert -
-
237 Jenne-jeno III unknown Suspected Expert -
-
238 Jenne-jeno IV unknown Suspected Expert -
-
239 Mali Empire unknown Suspected Expert -
-
240 Songhai Empire - Askiya Dynasty absent Confident Expert -
-
241 Early Mongols absent Confident Expert -
-
242 Later Wagadu Empire absent Inferred Expert -
-
243 Middle Wagadu Empire unknown Suspected Expert -
-
244 Indo-Greek Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
245 Kachi Plain - Pre-Urban Period absent Confident Expert -
-
246 Kachi Plain - Proto-Historic Period absent Confident Expert -
-
247 Late Roman Republic absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
248 Roman Empire - Principate absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
249 Japan - Incipient Jomon absent Confident Expert -
Paper currency first introduced in the 1600s [1] .

[1]: (Snodgrass 2003, 254)


250 Japan - Initial Jomon absent Confident Expert -
Paper currency first introduced in the 1600s [1] .

[1]: (Snodgrass 2003, 254)


251 Japan - Early Jomon absent Inferred Expert -
Paper currency first introduced in the 1600s [1] .

[1]: (Snodgrass 2003, 254)


252 Japan - Late Jomon absent Confident Expert -
Paper currency first introduced in the 1600s [1] .

[1]: (Snodgrass 2003, 254)


253 OOpsian absent Confident Expert -
The Fukui domain was the first to issue paper currency, doing so in 1661, and other domains followed this practice.’ [1]

[1]: Deal, William E. 2005. Handbook to Life in Medieval and Early Modern Japan. Oxford University Press.p.126.


254 Kara-Khanids absent Inferred Expert -
Had paper. need to check whether paper formed the basis of any financial instruments within the banking system that could be called money.
255 Funan I absent Confident Expert -
Barter was the normal market exchange mechanism. After the Angkor period, gold coins marked with symbols made their appearance, but until then gold or silver ingots with measured weights functioned as currency (the earliest evidence of the use of bullion in exchange dates from the period of the "Fu-nan").’ [1]

[1]: (Mabbett and Chandler 1995, p.176)


256 Eastern Turk Khaganate absent Confident Expert -
According to personal communication with N. Kradin. [1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


257 Late Mongols absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


258 Shiwei absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


259 Second Turk Khaganate absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


260 Uigur Khaganate absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


261 Late Xiongnu absent Confident Expert -
According to personal communication with N. Kradin. [1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


262 Zungharian Empire absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


263 Monte Alban IIIB and IV absent Confident Expert -
Sources do not suggest that monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


264 Oaxaca - Rosario absent Confident Expert -
Sources do not suggest that monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


265 Kingdom of Norway II absent Confident Expert -
[1]

[1]: Júlíusson and Kristissen, pers. comm. 2017


266 Cuzco - Late Intermediate II absent Confident Expert -
According to Alan Covey: "No evidence of money. I don’t know how one would document “markets”—in the exchange sense or the spatial sense? There is not enough evidence to evaluate exchange systems in the Cuzco region before Inca times, and the study of Inca exchange is steeped in substantivist/Marxian ideology that downplays exchange." [1]

[1]: (Alan Covey 2015, personal communication)


267 Wari Empire absent Confident Expert -
The Wari were an empire without money [1]

[1]: (McEwan and Williams in Bergh 2012, 73)


268 Kachi Plain - Aceramic Neolithic absent Confident Expert -
No evidence of paper currency has been found in the archaeological record at Mehrgarh. [1]

[1]: Jarrige, J. F. (2008). Mehrgarh neolithic. Pragdhara, 18, 135-154.


269 Kachi Plain - Chalcolithic absent Confident Expert -
No evidence of paper currency has been found in the archaeological record at Mehrgarh. [1]

[1]: Jarrige, J. F. (2008). Mehrgarh neolithic. Pragdhara, 18, 135-154.


270 Sakha - Early absent Confident Expert -
-
271 Egypt - Kushite Period absent Inferred Expert -
-
272 Umayyad Caliphate absent Confident Expert -
-
273 Sarazm absent Confident Expert -
-
274 Fatimid Caliphate absent Confident Expert -
-
275 Konya Plain - Early Bronze Age unknown Suspected Expert -
-
276 Konya Plain - Late Bronze Age II absent Inferred Expert -
-
277 Middle Bronze Age in Central Anatolia unknown Suspected Expert -
-
278 Late Cappadocia absent Inferred Expert -
-
279 Konya Plain - Early Chalcolithic absent Inferred Expert -
-
280 Konya Plain - Late Chalcolithic unknown Suspected Expert -
-
281 East Roman Empire absent Confident Expert -
-
282 Hatti - New Kingdom absent Inferred Expert -
-
283 Hatti - Old Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
-
284 Kingdom of Lydia absent Confident Expert -
-
285 Lysimachus Kingdom absent Inferred Expert -
-
286 Konya Plain - Ceramic Neolithic absent Confident Expert -
-
287 Konya Plain - Early Neolithic absent Confident Expert -
-
288 Konya Plain - Late Neolithic absent Confident Expert -
-
289 Ottoman Emirate absent Confident Expert -
-
290 Ottoman Empire I absent Confident Expert -
-
291 Ottoman Empire II absent Confident Expert -
-
292 Ottoman Empire III absent Confident Expert -
-
293 Phrygian Kingdom unknown Suspected Expert -
-
294 Rum Sultanate absent Inferred Expert -
-
295 Tabal Kingdoms absent Confident Expert -
-
296 Cahokia - Lohman-Stirling absent Confident Expert -
-
297 Cahokia - Moorehead absent Confident Expert -
-
298 Early Illinois Confederation unknown Suspected Expert -
-
299 Haudenosaunee Confederacy - Early absent Confident Expert -
-
300 Cahokia - Early Woodland absent Confident Expert -
-
301 Cahokia - Emergent Mississippian II absent Confident Expert -
-
302 Cahokia - Late Woodland II absent Confident Expert -
-
303 Cahokia - Middle Woodland absent Confident Expert -
-
304 Cahokia - Late Woodland III absent Confident Expert -
-
305 Cahokia - Late Woodland I absent Confident Expert -
-
306 Cahokia - Sand Prairie absent Confident Expert -
-
307 Cahokia - Emergent Mississippian I absent Confident Expert -
-
308 Oneota absent Confident Expert -
-
309 Chagatai Khanate unknown Suspected Expert -
-
310 Khanate of Bukhara unknown Suspected Expert -
-
311 Koktepe I unknown Suspected Expert -
-
312 Koktepe II absent Confident Expert -
-
313 Himyar I absent Confident Expert -
-
314 Himyar II absent Confident Expert -
-
315 Yemen - Qasimid Dynasty absent Confident Expert -
-
316 Rasulid Dynasty absent Confident Expert -
-
317 Yemen Ziyad Dynasty absent Confident Expert -
-
318 Durrani Empire present Confident Expert -
Bills of exchange in Multan called hundi chalan. [1]

[1]: Hanifi, Shah. Connecting Histories in Afghanistan: Market Relations and State Formation on a Colonial Frontier. Stanford University Press, 2011. pp. 44-54


319 Hephthalites absent Confident Expert -
Coins and tokens, but not paper money, in circulation. [1]

[1]: Skaff, Jonathan Karam. "Sasanian and Arab-Sasanian Silver Coins from Turfan: Their Relationship to International Trade and the Local Economy." Asia Major 11, no. 2 (1998): pp. 67-115.


320 Eastern Han Empire absent Confident Expert -
"The Song dynasty introduced paper money in 1024 because China did not have enough silver or copper for its growing commercial economy." [1]

[1]: (Headrick 2009, 85)


321 Western Jin absent Inferred Expert -
"during the Western Jin and early Sixteen Kingdom periods paper spread westward and replaced woodslips". [1] - No mention of paper currency in this brief discussion of early Chinese paper making in this source.

[1]: (Xinjiang 2013, 424) Xinjiang, Rong. Galambos, Imre trans. 2013. Eighteen Lectures on Dunhuang. BRILL.


322 Great Ming present Confident Expert -
1375 CE: Hongwu Emperor issued banknotes (大明通行寶鈔) due to lack to copper; 1389 CE: The government issued more banknotes with smaller denomination. Inflation begun in the circulation market as the Ming did kept issuing banknotes but did not recycle the old ones. "The Ming halted the practice [of using paper money] in the mid-fifteenth century...The private sector moved to fill the void" [1]

[1]: (Eastman 1988, 111 ) Eastman, Lloyd. 1988. Family, Fields and Ancestors: Constancy and Change in China’s Social and Economic History 1550-1949. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


323 Sakha - Late absent Confident Expert -
No indigenously produced paper currency. Russian money also became an important medium of exchange: ’Yakut also engaged in the fur trade; by the twentieth century hunters for luxury furs had depleted the ermines, sables, and foxes, and they were relying on squirrels. Yakut merchants and transporters spread throughout the entire northeast, easing communications and trade for natives and Russians. They sold luxuries like silver and gold jewelry and carved bone, ivory, and wood crafts in addition to staples such as butter, meat, and hay. Barter, Russian money, and furs formed the media of exchange. Guns were imported, as was iron for local blacksmiths.’ [1] Fox, ermine, and deer skins were also sold for money: ’The Yakuts hunt foxes only in autumn and winter by setting up traps and self-released bows. Sometimes foxes get caught in the nooses set up to hares, but rarely perish in the noose trap, since the beam is not sufficiently quick to lift their weight. The fox eats everything: fish, meat, berries, roots, even the carrions of other foxes that got caught in the trap. The fox is far from being a rare animal in the north of the region: I saw one on several occasions near people’s houses and once witnessed a fox running across the yard of the yurta. A fox, especially the darker varieties which are larger, can be easily mistaken for a Yakut dog. The skin of the red fox serves in the north as a unit of exchange. It is priced between 2 and 5 rubles; sivodushka-between 6 & 15 rubles; and the black-brown variety between 25 and 50 rubles. I was shown very beautiful, perfectly black skins with a slight grizzle, for which 120 rubles was paid on the spot.’ [2] ’ERMINE (mustela erminea), kyrnas, belelyakh, is the animal most hunted for the purposes of trade. It is found in all parts of the country, on the tableland and in the tundra. Increase and decrease in the numbers of this animal depend probably on the amount of available food. In winter it comes near human dwellings, gets into the granaries, and eats and carriesaway meat and fish. It is caught by special traps called hlopushi (chirkan - a mouse trap). The ermine is a predatory, bold, and curious animal. When irritated it will attack even human beings. Cases are known of the ermine inflicting serious wounds on people, for it attempts to cut through the blood vessels on the neck, where it ascends with exceptional speed and agility. The ermine skin is priced between 2 and 5 cents and is used as the smallest exchange unit.’ [3] ’Deer meat is most delicious in September and October, and during this period the deer’s fur is regarded as at its best. The northern deer’s fur is considered warmer than that of the domesticated deer. On the spot the skin of the wild deer brings between 1 ruble and 2 rubles and 50 cents. The Yakuts hunt the deer with guns, or by setting up self-releasing bows. Pit-traps are not used by the Yakuts in hunting this or any other animal.’ [4] Russian money was also at least occasionally used in dealings among the Sakha themselves: ’I at least never heard anything about a wealthy shaman; on the contrary, the shaman often gets no more than 5 kopeks for healing a sick eye. And how little is this sum worth north of Yakutsk! Some Yakuts refused to accept a twenty kopeks coin for a hazel-hen I wanted to buy, saying that they could not manage to use the money; if it had an eye, they would have used it as a button; but as there was no such, I was to take it back. The smallest unit for them is the ruble.’ [5]

[1]: Balzer, Marjorie Mandelstam and Skoggard, Ian: eHRAF Cultural Summary for the Yakut

[2]: Sieroszewski, Wacław 1993. “Yakut: An Experiment In Ethnographic Research”, 275

[3]: Sieroszewski, Wacław 1993. “Yakut: An Experiment In Ethnographic Research”, 280

[4]: Sieroszewski, Wacław 1993. “Yakut: An Experiment In Ethnographic Research”, 290

[5]: Priklonski, Vasilij, and Friedrich S. Krauss 1888. “Shamanism Among The Yakut", 175


324 Ayutthaya absent Confident Expert -
"Machine-minted coins and printed paper money appeared in 1862, when the imported cowries were officially taken out of circulation." [1]

[1]: (Van Dongen, no publication year, p. 10)


325 Byzantine Empire I absent Confident Expert -
Preiser-Kapeller says absent. [1]

[1]: (Johannes Preiser-Kapeller 2015) Institute for Medieval Research, Division of Byzantine Research, Austrian Academy of Sciences)


326 Roman Empire - Dominate absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
327 Ancient Khwarazm absent Confident Expert -
"Finally, the Greeks gave to Sogdiana its first real coinage, because Achaemenid darics are nearly absent from Sogdiana, as they are from all of eastern Iran. " [1]

[1]: (De la Vaissière 2005, 18)


328 Sogdiana - City-States Period absent Inferred Expert -
Not mentioned by De la Vaissière in his discussion of Sogdian money. [1]

[1]: (De la Vaissière 2005, 171-174)


329 Northern Song present Confident Expert -
"Although both qianyin and huizi functioned as de facto paper money, they still preserved certain features of the instrument of credit that allowed for a close connection with the financial market." [1] "There were two key reasons for the success of qianyin in the twelfth century: first, like its antecedent the jiaozi voucher, qianyin was redeemable by the government; second, the Sichuan administration recognized it as a means of payment. Soldiers used it to purchase goods on the market after receiving their qianyin-paid salaries, and farmers and merchants used it to pay taxes.This policy turned qianyin into a paper money and certainly increased the real size of the money supply." [1] However, the qianin and huizi played a greater role in the Southern Song after 1130 CE because "as the Song court could maintain a budgetary balance during the centuries prior to 1125, it did not seriously exploit the credit instruments for waging war." [2]

[1]: (Liu 2015, 70)

[2]: (Liu 2015, 69-70)


330 Classical Angkor absent Confident Expert -
’The Khmer empire never developed a standardized currency, instead using exchange equivalents in gold, silver, rice, cloth, cattle, butter and slaves (Sedov 1978:125), and remained a marginal player in the China-Southeast Asia trade network.’ [1] ’The economy of Angkor, now receiving detailed scholarly attention is somewhat peculiar because, unlike most neighbouring states, the empire never used money of any kind.’ [2]

[1]: (Stark, Miriam 2010, p. 161)

[2]: (Chandler 2008, p.9)


331 Early Qing present Confident Expert -
Qing issued paper currency in both Shunzhi and Xianfeng regime. “Although Chinese had begun using paper money during the Song Dynasty, the Ming had halted the practice in the mid-fifteenth century. Thereafter, except for two brief returns to paper currency by the Qing, in the Xunzhi (1644-61) and the Xianfeng (1851-61) reigns, no Chinese government again issued paper currency until the early twentieth century. The private sector moved to fill the void, and during the 100 or so years before the Opium War, several different instruments of currency, such as bank drafts were used to facilitate currency exchange. True paper money began circulating after various banks and money-changing shops issued paper receipts for deposits for silver and copper; these receipts, backed by a 100 percent reserve, soon began circulating as money.” [1]

[1]: (Eastman 1988, 111) Eastman, Lloyd. 1988. Family, Fields and Ancestors: Constancy and Change in China’s Social and Economic History 1550-1949. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


332 Late Qing present Confident Expert -
Qing issued paper currency in both Shunzhi and Xianfeng regime. “Although Chinese had begun using paper money during the Song Dynasty, the Ming had halted the practice in the mid-fifteenth century. Thereafter, except for two brief returns to paper currency by the Qing, in the Xunzhi (1644-61) and the Xianfeng (1851-61) reigns, no Chinese government again issued paper currency until the early twentieth century. The private sector moved to fill the void, and during the 100 or so years before the Opium War, several different instruments of currency, such as bank drafts were used to facilitate currency exchange. True paper money began circulating after various banks and money-changing shops issued paper receipts for deposits for silver and copper; these receipts, backed by a 100 percent reserve, soon began circulating as money” [1]

[1]: (Eastman 1988, 111) Eastman, Lloyd. 1988. Family, Fields and Ancestors: Constancy and Change in China’s Social and Economic History 1550-1949. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


333 Tang Dynasty I absent Inferred Expert -
No true paper money, however merchants could carry "feiqian (literally, "flying money"), a government-issued document that was redeemable on presentation at any of the provincial treasuries." [1]

[1]: (Cheng 2003, 10) Cheng, Linsun. Banking in Modern China: Entrepreneurs, Professional Managers, and the Development of Chinese Banks, 1897-1937. Cambridge University Press.


334 Western Zhou absent Confident Expert -
Not until a later time. "All scholars agree that neither money nor a clear concept of private land ownership existed during the Western Zhou period." [1]

[1]: (Zhao 2015, 76) Zhao, Dingxin. 2015. The Confucian-Legalist State: A New Theory of Chinese History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.


335 Great Yuan present Confident Expert -
"The Ministry of Revenue was charged with overseeing population cen- suses, taxation records, state treasuries, currency, and government manufac- turing. One of this ministry’s most important duties was enforcing the numerous and elaborate Yiian regulations concerning paper currency. Be- cause the Yiian government was committed to the empirewide circulation of paper notes, the procedures necessary for printing and administering paper currency were extensive. The government’s deep concern is suggested by the fact that counterfeiting paper money was punishable by death." [1]

[1]: (Endicott-West 1994, 589)


336 Shuar - Ecuadorian absent Confident Expert -
No indigenously produced paper money. According to SCCS variable 17 ’Money (Media of Exchange) and Credit’, ‘1’ or ’No media of exchange or money’ was present, not ’Domestically used articles as media of exchange’ or ’Tokens of conventional value as media of exchange’ or ’Foreign coinage or paper coinage’, or ’Indigenous coinage or paper currency’. Rivet reports some monetization of the tsantsa trade: ’The first tsantsas coming to Europe had their hour [72] of renown and attained extraordinary prices. In 1865, one of them was sold for 1500 francs ( ). Ten years ago another was sold at auction for 500 francs at the Hotél Drouot ( ). Actually, these objects are much less rare and have lost a part of their commercial value. At Macas, at Gualaquiza and at Zamora, the whites buy them directly from the Indians for ten sucres, that is 25 francs, and take them to Cuenca, Riobamba and Loja, where they resell them for 30 to 50 sucres, that is 75 to 125 francs. In Europe, the best examples are worth 200 and 300 francs and there is not an important museum that does not possess at least one. In Paris, the Museum of Natural History has five of them, the Anthropological Society one, the Ethnographic Museum of the Trocadero three, the Army Museum one, and also there are a good number in private collections.’ [1] It remains to be confirmed how common this was in direct exchanges between settlers/traders and Indians.

[1]: Rivet, Paul 1908. “Jivaro Indians: Geographic, Historical And Ethnographic Research”, 71p


337 Spanish Empire I absent Confident Expert -
Banknotes were introduced in 1780 [1]

[1]: (Payne 1973, 365) Payne, Stanley G. 1973. A History of Spain and Portugal, Volume 2, Madison, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press. http://libro.uca.edu/payne2/spainport2.htm https://www.zotero.org/groups/seshat_databank/items/itemKey/Z6EHG6PP


338 Japan - Final Jomon absent Confident Expert -
Paper currency first introduced in the 1600s [1] .

[1]: (Snodgrass 2003, 254)


339 Kamakura Shogunate absent Confident Expert -
’The Fukui domain was the first to issue paper currency, doing so in 1661, and other domains followed this practice.’ [1]

[1]: Deal, William E. 2005. Handbook to Life in Medieval and Early Modern Japan. Oxford University Press.p.126.


340 Kassite Babylonia absent Confident Expert -
"The Mesopotamians did not use coinage (invented in Asia Minor in the seventh century B.C.E.) but employed various commodities as media of exchange and measures of value: occasionally gold, copper, and tin, but most commonly silver and grain. The value of goods entrusted to merchants was reckoned in weights of silver or volumes of barley, as was that of the commodities that the merchants brought back from their expeditions. Silver rings, coils of silver wire that could easily be cut into pieces, and other small units (often of 5 shekels weight) were regularly used in transactions, the requisite quantity of silver being weighed out to make a purchase or pay for a service." [1]

[1]: (McIntosh 2005: 132) McIntosh, J. 2005. Ancient Mesopotamia: New Perspective. Santa Barbara: ABC Clio. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/itemKey/KK2E3KMD.


341 Us Reconstruction-Progressive present Confident -
Paper currency in the form of Treasury Notes, began to be issued in order to fund the War of 1812. [1]

[1]: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/United_States_dollar


342 Chuuk - Late Truk present Confident Expert -
According to SCCS variable 17 ’Money (Media of Exchange) and Credit’, ’4’ Foreign coinage or paper currency was present, not ‘1’ ’No media of exchange or money’, ’Domestically used articles as media of exchange’ or ’Tokens of conventional value as media of exchange’ or ’Indigenous coinage or paper currency’. Money was introduced by the colonial administration: ’The impact of these economic changes upon the Trukese was great. Just as under the Germans law and order were made the province of the administration, a step which can be reversed (without chaos) only by a long and intelligently directed course of evolution, so under the Japanese the step to a money economy and dependence upon some categories of imported goods was carried far enough beyond the German beginnings so that it too has become irreversible. While the Trukese were not indoctrinated in the more skilled techniques, such as deep-sea fishing and boat-building, there were many jobs available at manual labor, an ever-increasing flow of trade goods upon which to spend the earnings thereof, and head taxes to assure that those who did not work cut copra. The Trukese began to travel more and more on Japanese boats (many of which they have now taken over and operate), to use a wider variety of Japanese tools, to eat (although not depend upon) rice and canned fish, and to wear clothese exclusively of foreign material.’ [1] Barter was not displaced entirely.

[1]: Gladwin, Thomas, and Seymour Bernard Sarason 1953. “Truk: Man In Paradise”, 43


343 British Empire II present Confident Expert -
"The fact is, that the paper currency of the country cannot be on a perfectly sound footing until the issue of notes, whether by joint stock banks or private individuals, be suppressed. ... A paper currency is not in a sound or wholesome state, unless, 1st, means be taken to insure that each particular note or parcel of such currency be paid immediately on demand; and unless, 2nd, the whole currency vary in amount and value exactly as a metallic currency would do were the paper currency withdrawn and coins substituted in its stead. The last condition is quite as indispensable to the existence of a well-established currency as the former; and it is one that cannot be fuilly realized otherwise than by confining the issue of paper to a single source. It is easy to see that were paper issued only by the Bank of England, or some one source in London, and then only in exchange for bullion, the currency would be in its most perfect state, and would fluctuate exactly as it would do were it wholly metallic. But at present the currency is supplied by hundreds of individuals and associations, all actuated by diferent and frequently conflicting views and interests." [1]

[1]: (McCulloch 1847, 37) J R McCulloch. 1847. A Descriptive and Statistical Account of the British Empire. Third Edition. Volume II. Longman, Brown, Green, and Longmans. London.


344 Hawaii I absent Confident Expert -
’Needless to say, there was no money (in Diamond’s words, no "abstract, intrinsically valueless medium for appropriating surplus, storing value, and deferring payment or delaying exchange") in precontact Hawai’i’. [1]

[1]: (Trask 1983, 99) Haunani-Kay Trask. 1983. ’Cultures in Collision: Hawai’i and England, 1778’. Pacific Studies 7 (1): 91-117.


345 Hawaii II absent Confident Expert -
’Needless to say, there was no money (in Diamond’s words, no "abstract, intrinsically valueless medium for appropriating surplus, storing value, and deferring payment or delaying exchange") in precontact Hawai’i’. [1]

[1]: (Trask 1983, 99) Haunani-Kay Trask. 1983. ’Cultures in Collision: Hawai’i and England, 1778’. Pacific Studies 7 (1): 91-117.


346 Hawaii III absent Confident Expert -
’Needless to say, there was no money (in Diamond’s words, no "abstract, intrinsically valueless medium for appropriating surplus, storing value, and deferring payment or delaying exchange") in precontact Hawai’i’. [1]

[1]: (Trask 1983, 99) Haunani-Kay Trask. 1983. ’Cultures in Collision: Hawai’i and England, 1778’. Pacific Studies 7 (1): 91-117.


347 Delhi Sultanate present Inferred Expert -
"The production of paper gave rise to increased record keeping in government offices, and to the widespread use of bills of exchange called hundis." [1]

[1]: (Ahmed 2011, 101) Ahmed, Farooqui Salma. 2011. A Comprehensive History of Medieval India: Twelfth to the Mid-Eighteenth Century. Pearson Education India.


348 Early A'chik absent Confident Expert -
After the introduction of foreign currency, barter was increasingly displaced by monetized exchange, but did not die out completely. Brass objects were particularly valuable. But this process did not predate colonization: ‘One of the significant economic transition brought about by the development of markets in Garo Hills is the gradual change over from barter to money economy.’ [1] During the colonial and early independence periods, barter trade was gradually displaced by monetized exchange. The coins and bank notes used were of Koch, colonial and national origin. ‘This shows how due to the adoption of permanent cultivation the cash income position from crop sales in Wajadagiri has improved.’ [2]

[1]: Alam, K. 1995. “Markets Of Garo Hills: An Assessment Of Their Socio-Economic Implications”, 112

[2]: Majumdar, Dhirendra Narayan 1978. “Culture Change In Two Garo Villages”, 106


349 Late A'chik present Confident Expert -
According to SCCS variable 17 ’Money (Media of Exchange) and Credit’ is coded as ’Foreign coinage or paper currency’ ‘One of the significant economic transition brought about by the development of markets in Garo Hills is the gradual change over from barter to money economy.’ [1] Cash crops, such as cotton, are sold at local markets. During the colonial and early independence periods, barter trade was gradually displaced by monetized exchange. The coins and bank notes used were of Koch, colonial and national origin. ‘This shows how due to the adoption of permanent cultivation the cash income position from crop sales in Wajadagiri has improved.’ [2]

[1]: Alam, K. 1995. “Markets Of Garo Hills: An Assessment Of Their Socio-Economic Implications”, 112

[2]: Majumdar, Dhirendra Narayan 1978. “Culture Change In Two Garo Villages”, 106


350 Mahajanapada era absent Inferred Expert -
"Gift-giving and receiving do not rule out other kinds of exchange, but trade in the Rig Vedic context was probably minimal. Barter was the mode of exchange and cattle an important unit of value. The word nishka seems to have meant ’a piece of gold’ or ’gold necklace’, and there is no indication of the use of coins." [1]

[1]: Singh, U. (2008) A History of Ancient and Early Medieval India, From the Stone Age to the 12th Century. Dorling Kindersley: Delhi. p191


351 Kansai - Kofun Period absent Confident Expert -
The Fukui domain was the first to issue paper currency, doing so in 1661, and other domains followed this practice.’ [1]

[1]: Deal, William E. 2005. Handbook to Life in Medieval and Early Modern Japan. Oxford University Press.p.126.


352 Saffarid Caliphate absent Confident -
Dirhams and dinars were issued as coins only. [1]

[1]: Frye 2007: 118. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/7XE9P8HB


353 Napoleonic France present Confident -
-
354 Bazi Dynasty absent Confident Expert -
"The Mesopotamians did not use coinage (invented in Asia Minor in the seventh century B.C.E.) but employed various commodities as media of exchange and measures of value: occasionally gold, copper, and tin, but most commonly silver and grain. The value of goods entrusted to merchants was reckoned in weights of silver or volumes of barley, as was that of the commodities that the merchants brought back from their expeditions. Silver rings, coils of silver wire that could easily be cut into pieces, and other small units (often of 5 shekels weight) were regularly used in transactions, the requisite quantity of silver being weighed out to make a purchase or pay for a service." [1]

[1]: (McIntosh 2005: 132) McIntosh, J. 2005. Ancient Mesopotamia: New Perspective. Santa Barbara: ABC Clio. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/itemKey/KK2E3KMD.


355 Dynasty of E absent Confident Expert -
"The Mesopotamians did not use coinage (invented in Asia Minor in the seventh century B.C.E.) but employed various commodities as media of exchange and measures of value: occasionally gold, copper, and tin, but most commonly silver and grain. The value of goods entrusted to merchants was reckoned in weights of silver or volumes of barley, as was that of the commodities that the merchants brought back from their expeditions. Silver rings, coils of silver wire that could easily be cut into pieces, and other small units (often of 5 shekels weight) were regularly used in transactions, the requisite quantity of silver being weighed out to make a purchase or pay for a service." [1]

[1]: (McIntosh 2005: 132) McIntosh, J. 2005. Ancient Mesopotamia: New Perspective. Santa Barbara: ABC Clio. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/itemKey/KK2E3KMD.


356 Second Dynasty of Isin absent Confident Expert -
"The Mesopotamians did not use coinage (invented in Asia Minor in the seventh century B.C.E.) but employed various commodities as media of exchange and measures of value: occasionally gold, copper, and tin, but most commonly silver and grain. The value of goods entrusted to merchants was reckoned in weights of silver or volumes of barley, as was that of the commodities that the merchants brought back from their expeditions. Silver rings, coils of silver wire that could easily be cut into pieces, and other small units (often of 5 shekels weight) were regularly used in transactions, the requisite quantity of silver being weighed out to make a purchase or pay for a service." [1]

[1]: (McIntosh 2005: 132) McIntosh, J. 2005. Ancient Mesopotamia: New Perspective. Santa Barbara: ABC Clio. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/itemKey/KK2E3KMD.


357 Neo-Babylonian Empire absent Confident Expert -
"The Mesopotamians did not use coinage (invented in Asia Minor in the seventh century B.C.E.) but employed various commodities as media of exchange and measures of value: occasionally gold, copper, and tin, but most commonly silver and grain. The value of goods entrusted to merchants was reckoned in weights of silver or volumes of barley, as was that of the commodities that the merchants brought back from their expeditions. Silver rings, coils of silver wire that could easily be cut into pieces, and other small units (often of 5 shekels weight) were regularly used in transactions, the requisite quantity of silver being weighed out to make a purchase or pay for a service." [1]

[1]: (McIntosh 2005: 132) McIntosh, J. 2005. Ancient Mesopotamia: New Perspective. Santa Barbara: ABC Clio. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/itemKey/KK2E3KMD.


358 Elam - Crisis Period absent Confident Expert -
"Coins turn up in the eastern Mediterranean in early sixth-century archaeological context and gradually begin circulating widely but are not archaeologically attested in Mesopotamia until well over two centuries later, at the end of the Achaemenid period." [1]

[1]: (Powell 1996, 225-226)


359 Ilkhanate present Confident Expert -
Geikhatu’s minster Sadr al-Din issued paper money along Chinese lines the chao, following concerns about the lack of funds in the royal treasury. These paper certificates had Chinese character printed on them and the Muslim confession of faith. [1]

[1]: Morgan, David. The Mongols. 2nd ed. The Peoples of Europe. Malden, MA ; Oxford: Blackwell Publishing, 2007, P.145.


360 Papal States - Early Modern Period I absent Confident Expert -
Although by this period international banking had reached a level of complexity by which towns like Florence often used bills of sale and credit in a way similar to paper currency, paper currency made by central banks did not exist yet.
361 Papal States - Early Modern Period II present Inferred Expert -
I have not found any clear evidence of paper currency, but letters of credit and bills of exchange were sophisticated enough by this point to count as paper currency.
362 Early Roman Republic absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
363 Middle Roman Republic absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
364 Roman Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
The Romans did not use paper currency in any period.
365 Ashikaga Shogunate absent Confident Expert -
’The Fukui domain was the first to issue paper currency, doing so in 1661, and other domains followed this practice.’ [1]

[1]: Deal, William E. 2005. Handbook to Life in Medieval and Early Modern Japan. Oxford University Press.p.126.


366 Heian absent Confident Expert -
’The Fukui domain was the first to issue paper currency, doing so in 1661, and other domains followed this practice.’ [1]

[1]: Deal, William E. 2005. Handbook to Life in Medieval and Early Modern Japan. Oxford University Press.p.126.


367 Tokugawa Shogunate present Confident Expert -
‘paper currency was used only on a limited basis in the early modern period. When paper money was issued, it was done by individual domains for use only within that region, despite the fact that the value of this paper money was pegged to the shogunate’s national currency system. The Fukui domain was the first to issue paper currency, doing so in 1661, and other domains followed this practice.’ [1]

[1]: Deal, William E. 2005. Handbook to Life in Medieval and Early Modern Japan. Oxford University Press.p.126.


368 Early Angkor absent Confident Expert -
’The Khmer empire never developed a standardized currency, instead using exchange equivalents in gold, silver, rice, cloth, cattle, butter and slaves (Sedov 1978:125), and remained a marginal player in the China-Southeast Asia trade network.’ [1] ’The economy of Angkor, now receiving detailed scholarly attention is somewhat peculiar because, unlike most neighbouring states, the empire never used money of any kind.’ [2] ’Some major differences between the pre-Angkor and Angkor peri- ods include the transfer of the center of power and population from southeast to northwest Cambodia (see map 4); the title pon disap- peared; inscriptions adopted a different format; new names were used for deities; and new words for economic subjects appeared. The system of coinage used in early Cambodia was discontinued; the Angkor period economy was moneyless.’ [3]

[1]: (Stark, Miriam 2010, p. 161)

[2]: (Chandler 2008, p.9)

[3]: (Miksic 2007, p. 82)


369 Late Angkor absent Confident Expert -
’The Khmer empire never developed a standardized currency, instead using exchange equivalents in gold, silver, rice, cloth, cattle, butter and slaves (Sedov 1978:125), and remained a marginal player in the China-Southeast Asia trade network.’ [1] ’The economy of Angkor, now receiving detailed scholarly attention is somewhat peculiar because, unlike most neighbouring states, the empire never used money of any kind.’ [2]

[1]: (Stark, Miriam 2010, p. 161)

[2]: (Chandler 2008, p.9)


370 Khmer Kingdom absent Confident Expert -
’The Khmer empire never developed a standardized currency, instead using exchange equivalents in gold, silver, rice, cloth, cattle, butter and slaves (Sedov 1978:125), and remained a marginal player in the China-Southeast Asia trade network.’ [1] ’The economy of Angkor, now receiving detailed scholarly attention is somewhat peculiar because, unlike most neighbouring states, the empire never used money of any kind.’ [2]

[1]: (Stark, Miriam 2010, p. 161)

[2]: (Chandler 2008, p.9)


371 Chenla absent Confident Expert -
’Strong evidence against the importance of trade or markets is the absence of money in post-6th-century Cambodia in contrast to Funan which had coinage’ [1] ’Neither is there reference to coinage, although precious metals are mentioned as objects of exchanges among donors and temples. The lack of coinage seems confirmed by the inability of archaeologists or architects excavating and restoring temples to discover any coins which may be dated between the end of the Funan and the post-Angkor period.’ [2]

[1]: (Vickery 1998, 314)

[2]: (Vickery 1998, 275)


372 Funan II absent Confident Expert -
Barter was the normal market exchange mechanism. After the Angkor period, gold coins marked with symbols made their appearance, but until then gold or silver ingots with measured weights functioned as currency (the earliest evidence of the use of bullion in exchange dates from the period of the "Fu-nan").’ [1]

[1]: (Mabbett and Chandler 1995, p.176)


373 Mongol Empire absent Confident Expert -
Chinese paper currency was present, but no indigenous [1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


374 Rouran Khaganate absent Confident Expert -
According to personal communication with N. Kradin. [1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


375 Xianbei Confederation absent Confident Expert -
According to personal communication with N. Kradin. [1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


376 Early Xiongnu absent Inferred Expert -
[1] Later Xiongnu Imperial Confederation coded absent.

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


377 Xiongnu Imperial Confederation absent Confident Expert -
According to personal communication with N. Kradin. [1]

[1]: (Kradin 2015, personal communication)


378 Early Monte Alban I absent Confident Expert -
Sources do not suggest that monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


379 Monte Alban Late I absent Confident Expert -
Sources do not suggest that monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


380 Monte Alban II absent Confident Expert -
Sources do not suggest that monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


381 Monte Alban III absent Confident Expert -
Sources do not suggest that monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


382 Monte Alban V absent Confident Expert -
Monetary items have not been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


383 Early Formative Basin of Mexico absent Confident Expert -
The system closest to coinage ever practiced in Mesoamerica was the widespread use of cacao beans and copper axes as media of exchange during the Postclassic. [1]

[1]: Berdan, Frances F., Marilyn A. Masson, Janine Gasco, and Michael E. Smith. (2003) "An International Economy." In Michael E. Smith and Frances F. Berdan (eds.) The Postclassic Mesoamerican World. Salt Lake City: The University of Utah Press, pg. 102.


384 Nkore absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


385 Late Formative Basin of Mexico absent Confident Expert -
Raw or manufatured prestige goods -- ceramics, precious stone, feathers, textiles, jewelry, ornaments, etc. (both "articles" like jade and feathers, and "tokens" like shells) -- likely functioned as "primitive money" or "social currency." [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]

[1]: Piña Chan, Román. (1971). "Preclassic or Formative Pottery and Minor Arts of the Valley of Mexico." In The Handbook of Middle American Indians, vol. 10, ed. G. F. Ekholm, and I. Bernal. Austin: University of Texas Press, pp.157-178.

[2]: Sanders, William T., Jeffrey R. Parsons, and Robert S. Santley. (1979) The Basin of Mexico: Ecological Processes in the Evolution of a Civilization. Academic Press, New York, pg. 331-3.

[3]: Stoner, Wesley D., Deborah L. Nichols, Bridget A. Alex, and Destiny L. Crider. (2015)"The emergence of Early-Middle Formative exchange patterns in Mesoamerica: A view from Altica in the Teotihuacan Valley." Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 39: 19-35.

[4]: Charlton, Thomas H. (1984). "Production and Exchange: Variables in the Evolution of a Civilization." In Kenneth G. Hirth (Ed.) Trade and Exchange in Early Mesoamerica. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, pp.17-42.

[5]: Hirth, Kenneth G. (1984). "Early Exchange in Mesoamerica: An Introduction." In Kenneth G. Hirth (Ed.) Trade and Exchange in Early Mesoamerica. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, pp.1-16.


386 Middle Formative Basin of Mexico absent Confident Expert -
The system closest to coinage ever practiced in Mesoamerica was the widespread use of cacao beans and copper axes as media of exchange during the Postclassic. [1]

[1]: Berdan, Frances F., Marilyn A. Masson, Janine Gasco, and Michael E. Smith. (2003) "An International Economy." In Michael E. Smith and Frances F. Berdan (eds.) The Postclassic Mesoamerican World. Salt Lake City: The University of Utah Press, pg. 102.


387 Terminal Formative Basin of Mexico absent Confident Expert -
Raw or manufatured prestige goods -- ceramics, precious stone, feathers, textiles, jewelry, ornaments, etc. (both "articles" like jade and feathers, and "tokens" like shells) -- likely functioned as "primitive money" or "social currency." [1] [2] [3] [4] [5]

[1]: Piña Chan, Román. (1971). "Preclassic or Formative Pottery and Minor Arts of the Valley of Mexico." In The Handbook of Middle American Indians, vol. 10, ed. G. F. Ekholm, and I. Bernal. Austin: University of Texas Press, pp.157-178.

[2]: Sanders, William T., Jeffrey R. Parsons, and Robert S. Santley. (1979) The Basin of Mexico: Ecological Processes in the Evolution of a Civilization. Academic Press, New York, pg. 331-3.

[3]: Stoner, Wesley D., Deborah L. Nichols, Bridget A. Alex, and Destiny L. Crider. (2015)"The emergence of Early-Middle Formative exchange patterns in Mesoamerica: A view from Altica in the Teotihuacan Valley." Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 39: 19-35.

[4]: Charlton, Thomas H. (1984). "Production and Exchange: Variables in the Evolution of a Civilization." In Kenneth G. Hirth (Ed.) Trade and Exchange in Early Mesoamerica. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, pp.17-42.

[5]: Hirth, Kenneth G. (1984). "Early Exchange in Mesoamerica: An Introduction." In Kenneth G. Hirth (Ed.) Trade and Exchange in Early Mesoamerica. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, pp.1-16.


388 Oaxaca - San Jose absent Confident Expert -
Although exchange of goods will have taken place, sources do not suggest that specific monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


389 Oaxaca - Tierras Largas absent Confident Expert -
Although exchange of goods will have taken place, sources do not suggest that specific monetary items have been found dating to this period. [1]

[1]: Marcus and Flannery (1996) Zapotec Civilization: How urban society evolved in Mexico’s Oaxaca Valley. Flannery and Marcus (1983) The Cloud People: divergent evolution of the Zapotec and Mixtec civilizations. Museum of Anthropology, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Academic Press, New York.


390 Cuzco - Early Intermediate I absent Confident Expert -
According to Alan Covey: "No evidence of money. I don’t know how one would document “markets”—in the exchange sense or the spatial sense? There is not enough evidence to evaluate exchange systems in the Cuzco region before Inca times, and the study of Inca exchange is steeped in substantivist/Marxian ideology that downplays exchange." [1]

[1]: (Alan Covey 2015, personal communication)


391 Cuzco - Early Intermediate II absent Confident Expert -
According to Alan Covey: "No evidence of money. I don’t know how one would document “markets”—in the exchange sense or the spatial sense? There is not enough evidence to evaluate exchange systems in the Cuzco region before Inca times, and the study of Inca exchange is steeped in substantivist/Marxian ideology that downplays exchange." [1]

[1]: (Alan Covey 2015, personal communication)


392 Cuzco - Late Intermediate I absent Confident Expert -
According to Alan Covey: "No evidence of money. I don’t know how one would document “markets”—in the exchange sense or the spatial sense? There is not enough evidence to evaluate exchange systems in the Cuzco region before Inca times, and the study of Inca exchange is steeped in substantivist/Marxian ideology that downplays exchange." [1]

[1]: (Alan Covey 2015, personal communication)


393 Cuzco - Late Formative absent Confident Expert -
According to Alan Covey: "No evidence of money. I don’t know how one would document “markets”—in the exchange sense or the spatial sense? There is not enough evidence to evaluate exchange systems in the Cuzco region before Inca times, and the study of Inca exchange is steeped in substantivist/Marxian ideology that downplays exchange." [1]

[1]: (Alan Covey 2015, personal communication)


394 Inca Empire absent Inferred Expert -
"Another important difference lay in the long-time presence of special-purpose money and more sophisticated weights and measures than those found in the central Andean highlands. It is not clear how widely the currencies were used in prehistory. There is no evidence, for example, that land or labor could be purchased until the Colonial era (Hosler et al. 1990; Salomon 1986; 1987; Netherly 1978). The Incas themselves did not adopt the currencies for the state economy, although they used large amounts of the shell and gold for political and ceremonial ends. Instead, they either left things alone or manipulated the situation politically to give favored groups an advantage." [1]

[1]: (D’Altroy 2014, 320)


395 Orokaiva - Colonial present Confident Expert -
According to SCCS variable 17 ’Money (Media of Exchange) and Credit’, ‘1’ or ’No media of exchange or money’ was present, not ’Domestically used articles as media of exchange’ or ’Tokens of conventional value as media of exchange’ or ’Foreign coinage or paper coinage’, or ’Indigenous coinage or paper currency’. Monetary exchange was introduced by the colonial powers: ’By the 1930s many Koropata men had been to gaol for disobeying one or other of the Native Regulations. Tax had been introduced before World War I and the consequent need for money was a powerful impetus for the planting of village cash crops and continued signing on for plantation work. In this decade more Koropatans were recruited to work on Kokoda rubber plantations, thus coming into contact with other Papuans. More of the villagers were becoming familiar with Papuans from other areas. The mission was known only by rumour until 1928 when the Anglicans bought 5 acres at Baravaturu. During the 1930s the more mobile Koropatans became acquainted with a kind of white man whose activities and objectives seemed to differ from those they had previously encountered, the missionary more interested in their beliefs than their labour power (Files 407, Karius in 409, 411; Box 6549, G91).’ [1]

[1]: Newton, Janice 1985. “Orokaiva Production And Change”, 57


396 Kachi Plain - Ceramic Neolithic absent Confident Expert -
No evidence of paper currency has been found in the archaeological record at Mehrgarh. [1]

[1]: Jarrige, J. F. (2008). Mehrgarh neolithic. Pragdhara, 18, 135-154.


397 Kachi Plain - Post-Urban Period absent Inferred Expert -
No evidence of paper currency has survived from Pirak. Only seal impressions on clay give any evidence of administrative records. [1]

[1]: Jarrige, J-F. (1979) Fouilles de Pirak. Paris : Diffusion de Boccard.


398 Kachi Plain - Urban Period I absent Confident Expert -
Neither coins nor paper currency were present in the Indus Valley at this time. [1]

[1]: Wright, R. P. (2010) The Ancient Indus: urbanism, economy and society. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. p260


399 Kachi Plain - Urban Period II absent Confident Expert -
Neither coins nor paper currency were present in the Indus Valley at this time. [1]

[1]: Wright, R. P. (2010) The Ancient Indus: urbanism, economy and society. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. p260


400 Byzantine Empire II absent Confident Expert -
Preiser-Kapeller says absent. [1]

[1]: (Preiser-Kapeller 2015) Institute for Medieval Research, Division of Byzantine Research, Austrian Academy of Sciences)


401 Byzantine Empire III absent Confident Expert -
Preiser-Kapeller says absent. [1]

[1]: (Preiser-Kapeller 2015) Institute for Medieval Research, Division of Byzantine Research, Austrian Academy of Sciences)


402 Haudenosaunee Confederacy - Late absent Confident Expert -
No indigeously produced paper money. During the reservation period, land and crops sales helped to generate monetary income: ’From 1790 until 1839, tribal and village government generally similar to that characteristic of the aboriginal era functioned. Local administration of justice and the allocation of lands among tribal members was in the hands of each of the tribal communities scattered along the banks of the Grand River. The Lower Cayuga had a treasury that dispensed with the proceeds of land sales. The Lower Mohawk too had a tribal fund which they jealously guarded (Canada, Six Nation Council Minutes, 1834-1839, P.A.C.R.G., 10). However, the Hereditary Council incroasingly assumed the autherity in what were previously tribal estates. In 1835 the council pressure from the Upper Mohawks led the Lower tribes to grant the Mohawks a share of the proceeds from the sale of Plaster beds.’ [1] The prior use of foreign currency in external trade cannot be ruled out.

[1]: Foley, Denis 1994. “Ethnohistoric And Ethnographic Analysis Of The Iroquois From The Aboriginal Era To The Present Suburban Era”, 176


403 Kingdom of Hawaii - Kamehameha Period absent Confident Expert -
"Taxes were not paid in money, but in the produce of the soil and in the various articles manufactured by the people, there being no native coinage and but very little foreign money in circulation." [1]

[1]: (Kuykendall 1938, 54)


404 Samanid Empire absent Inferred Expert -
Had paper. need to check whether paper formed the basis of any financial instruments within the banking system that could be called money.
405 Timurid Empire unknown Suspected Expert -
No data. The preceding Ilkhanate Mongols issued paper currency similar to the Chinese model of that era.
406 Yemen - Tahirid Dynasty absent Confident Expert -
This is based on the codes for the Rasulids as ’Sultan ’Amir also appears to have been emulating the high period of Rasulid power a hundred years earlier’ [1]

[1]: Porter, Venetia Ann (1992) The history and monuments of the Tahirid dynasty of the Yemen 858-923/1454-1517, Durham theses, Durham University, p. 4 Available at Durham E-Theses Online: http://etheses.dur.ac.uk/5867/


407 Early Modern Sierra Leone absent Confident -
The following suggests that paper currency was first introduced to the region in 1808. "From 1 January 1808 Freetown was administered by Whitehall and served as the residence of the British governor. The company coins were withdrawn with the transfer, with re-issues of only the ten-cent pieces in 1802, 1803 and 1805, by which date they had become extremely rare. The first governor specifically objected to the company currency because he believed its decimal denomination appealed to American republicanism. The company coins were immediately replaced with bills of ten, five and one dollars, and three months later with Governor Thompson’s own home-made treasury bills of five pounds and one pound sterling,38 whose issues spiralled out of control within two years of his appointment." [1]

[1]: (Mew 2016: 200) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/U3D2FQIH/collection.


408 Plantagenet England absent Confident -
There was no paper currency during this time. [1]

[1]: (Prestwich 2005: xxiii) Prestwich, Michael. 2005. Plantagenet England 1225-1360. Oxford: Oxford University Press. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/XTBKFDCI


409 Freetown absent Confident -
The following suggests that paper currency was first introduced in 1808. "From 1 January 1808 Freetown was administered by Whitehall and served as the residence of the British governor. The company coins were withdrawn with the transfer, with re-issues of only the ten-cent pieces in 1802, 1803 and 1805, by which date they had become extremely rare. The first governor specifically objected to the company currency because he believed its decimal denomination appealed to American republicanism. The company coins were immediately replaced with bills of ten, five and one dollars, and three months later with Governor Thompson’s own home-made treasury bills of five pounds and one pound sterling,38 whose issues spiralled out of control within two years of his appointment." [1]

[1]: (Mew 2016: 200) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/U3D2FQIH/collection.


410 Buganda absent Confident -
"As we have noted, pre-colonial Buganda never developed a purely monetary economy, and even during the later nineteenth century barter was an important method of exchange, existing alongside a cowry currency. Nevertheless, the information we have on nineteenth-century prices suggests that virtually everything had at least a nominal cowry value. Moreover, other currencies existed alongside cowries, and some undoubtedly pre-dated the latter. Roscoe mentions a "small ivory disc" which he terms ’sanga’, ssanga being the Luganda term for either a tusk or ivory in general. This, Roscoe claimed, was one of the earliest forms of money in Buganda; although clearly indigenous and probably much older than the cowry shell, it also had a cowry value. One disc was apparently worth one hundred shells. Ivory played a dual role insofar as it was on the one hand a commodity valued for its own sake, and on the other a standard medium of exchange. The former role gradually took precedence over the latter, as demand for ivory from the coast increased, so that as the nineteenth century progressed, ivory as money all but disappeared. [...] A third pre-cowry currency has already been mentioned, namely the blue bead, and as we have also already noted, examples of beads have been excavated at Ntusi. From such archaeological evidence, it is possible to suggest that beads may be the oldest currency in the region." [1]

[1]: (Reid 2010: 126-127) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/2H64W34U/collection.


411 Toro absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


412 Buganda absent Confident -
"As we have noted, pre-colonial Buganda never developed a purely monetary economy, and even during the later nineteenth century barter was an important method of exchange, existing alongside a cowry currency. Nevertheless, the information we have on nineteenth-century prices suggests that virtually everything had at least a nominal cowry value. Moreover, other currencies existed alongside cowries, and some undoubtedly pre-dated the latter. Roscoe mentions a "small ivory disc" which he terms ’sanga’, ssanga being the Luganda term for either a tusk or ivory in general. This, Roscoe claimed, was one of the earliest forms of money in Buganda; although clearly indigenous and probably much older than the cowry shell, it also had a cowry value. One disc was apparently worth one hundred shells. Ivory played a dual role insofar as it was on the one hand a commodity valued for its own sake, and on the other a standard medium of exchange. The former role gradually took precedence over the latter, as demand for ivory from the coast increased, so that as the nineteenth century progressed, ivory as money all but disappeared. [...] A third pre-cowry currency has already been mentioned, namely the blue bead, and as we have also already noted, examples of beads have been excavated at Ntusi. From such archaeological evidence, it is possible to suggest that beads may be the oldest currency in the region." [1]

[1]: (Reid 2010: 126-127) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/2H64W34U/collection.


413 Kingdom of Nyinginya absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


414 Ndorwa absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


415 Burundi absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


416 Mubari absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


417 Gisaka absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


418 Bugesera absent Confident -
"As we have seen, to secure their essential ties, the ancient states, lacking writing and money, relied on kinship, trust, and personal relationships, which were periodically rekindled by direct contact and exchanged words." [1]

[1]: (Chrétien 2006: 178) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/FXCVWDRI/collection.


419 Dutch Empire absent Confident -
-
420 Lombard Kingdom absent Confident -
Only metal coins were present.
421 Buhaya absent Confident -
"No single currency was in general use. Buhaya used cowrie shells, Ujiji employed special beads, and Pare utilised maize cobs, but none had a fixed value elsewhere." [1]

[1]: (Iliffe 1979: 68) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/SB2AJMVC/collection.


422 Kaabu absent Inferred -
The following suggests that the main items of currency were kola nuts, blue cloths, iron, wire, red coral, salt, glassware, wine, aguardiente. "[T]wo documents can in fact shed a great deal of light on the history of Kaabu. Both date from towards the end of the 17th century[...]. The first document is a list of the trade of the Portuguese and the important ports of the region between the Casamance river and Sierra Leone. [...] The author, Governor Rodrigo de Oliveira da Fonseca, states: ’In the Geba river it is possible to navigate almost forty leagues upstream in small boats; halfway up is the settlement of whites which has three hundred Christians including men, women and children; in all this inland interior there are a great number of blacks of diverse nations, all of them have come across the whites and cultivate cotton and many other crops which they sell to the whites together with many slaves and much ivory and wax and some gold and white cloths which the blacks bring from a long way inland and they exchange it for kola nuts which there is the best currency for exchange [genero]… and other good currencies in this whole region are blue cloths and iron and wire and fine red coral and salt…and aguardente is also well received”. [...] According to Castanho, the main items of exchange were kola nuts, followed by salt, glassware, and then items such as wine and aguardente. [1]

[1]: (Green 2009: 103) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/V2GTBN8A/collection.


423 Pre-Sape Sierra Leone absent Inferred -
"First, prior to the arrival of the first wave of [colonial] settlers [to Freetown in 1787] there existed no centralised currency system that resembled, for example, the gold dust of the Asante Kingdom (where the use of cowries was forbidden). Cowries were not generally much in use in the coastal and hinterland regions of Sierra Leone, and this led to acute problems in introducing coins that were of small enough denominations for local market transactions (in turn leading to problems with cut dollars in 1818)." [1]

[1]: (Mew 2016: 199( Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/U3D2FQIH/collection.


424 West Burkina Faso Red II and III absent Inferred -
The following suggests not only that cattle were no longer used as articles of exchange, but also the existence of system of exchange based on labor rather than physical currency. "By the middle of Red II this material symbol of inequality, cattle, ceased to be commonly kept, despite the emergence of a drier environment more suitable for animal husbandry in the second millennium A.D. Historically, cattle served as social capital in many non-centralized Voltaic societies, enabling marriages and funerary celebrations, and representing wealth. Consequently, the rejection of cattle, in addition to limiting the accumulation of wealth, may also indicate the beginning of matrimonial compensation in agricultural labor, typical of modern autonomous village societies." [1]

[1]: (Dueppen 2012: 30)


425 West Burkina Faso Red IV absent Inferred -
The following suggests not only that cattle were no longer used as articles of exchange, but also the existence of system of exchange based on labor rather than physical currency. "By the middle of Red II this material symbol of inequality, cattle, ceased to be commonly kept, despite the emergence of a drier environment more suitable for animal husbandry in the second millennium A.D. Historically, cattle served as social capital in many non-centralized Voltaic societies, enabling marriages and funerary celebrations, and representing wealth. Consequently, the rejection of cattle, in addition to limiting the accumulation of wealth, may also indicate the beginning of matrimonial compensation in agricultural labor, typical of modern autonomous village societies." [1]

[1]: (Dueppen 2012: 30)


426 Sape absent Inferred -
"First, prior to the arrival of the first wave of [colonial] settlers [to Freetown in 1787] there existed no centralised currency system that resembled, for example, the gold dust of the Asante Kingdom (where the use of cowries was forbidden). Cowries were not generally much in use in the coastal and hinterland regions of Sierra Leone, and this led to acute problems in introducing coins that were of small enough denominations for local market transactions (in turn leading to problems with cut dollars in 1818)." [1]

[1]: (Mew 2016: 199( Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/U3D2FQIH/collection.


427 Classical Ife absent Inferred -
The following suggests that strings, "standard measurements of beads" and possibly glass beads were used as "money". "Given their quality as a high-value and low-bulk commodity, long-distance travelers likely carried Ifè glass beads across the Yorùbá world and the adjacent areas as a means of payment for provisions on their journeys. The durability and affective qualities of these dichroic beads, especially the most common sègi, and the guarantee of their supply and demand encouraged people to use them as a means of high-value exchange and for storing wealth. We are short of evidence on whether glass beads evolved to serve as a standard currency, especially as a means of pricing. However, strings and other standard measurements of beads were likely used for purchasing high-value products and services." [1]

[1]: (Ogundiran 2020: 107-108)


428 Tudor and Early Stuart England absent Confident -
Bonds and bills of exchange were issued on paper but it was not currency. [1]

[1]: (Bucholz et al 2013: 328) Bucholz, Robert, Newton Key, and R.O. Bucholz. 2013. Early Modern England 1485-1714: A Narrative History. Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons. http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/uvic/detail.action?docID=1166775. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/XQGJH96U


429 Khwarezmid Empire absent Confident -
Dinar was a coin-based currency. [1]

[1]: Buniyatov 2015: 90-92. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/SAEVEJFH


430 Hohokam Culture absent Confident -
There was no currency but trade was based on an exchange system with their neighbours and other peoples who lived on the coast of North America. [1]

[1]: “The Ancestral Sonoran Desert People - Casa Grande Ruins National Monument (U.S. National Park Service),”. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/HZ95455H


431 Aro absent Inferred -
No reference to any indigenous paper currency being present, only traded items, slaves and brass rods. There may have been other forms of local currency, so can’t be certain. “From another historian we get the reasons for the Aro Expedition as follows: “Reasons for the war advanced by Sir Ralph Moore, the British High Commissioner of the Nigerian Coast Protectorate, included: To put a stop to slave dealing and the slave trade generally with a view to the Slave Dealing Proclamation No. 5 of 1901 being enforced throughout the entire territories as from first of January next; to abolish the Juju hierarchy of the Aro tribe, which by superstition and fraud causes much injustice among the coast tribes generally and is opposed to the establishment of Government. The power of the priesthood is also employed in obtaining natives for sale as slaves and it is essential to finally break it; to open up the country of the entire Aro to civilization; to induce the natives to engage in legitimate trade; to introduce a currency in lieu of slaves, brass rods, and other forms of native currency and to facilitate trade transactions; to eventually establish a labour market as a substitute to the present system of slavery”” [1]

[1]: Innocent, Rev. (2020). A Critical Study on the Ibini Ukpabi (Arochukwu Long Juju) Oracle and its Implications on the International Relations During the 20th Century. London Journal of Research in Humanities and Social Sciences, 20(10): 8. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/ZXZGZSM3/collection


432 Kanem-Borno absent Inferred -
Scholarship mentions several other types of money, but nothing about paper currency.
433 Benin Empire absent Inferred -
The following quote suggests that the main form of currency was cowrie shells. “The reign of Oba Esigie witnessed the increasing monetisation of the enclave economy (cowries), and provided the opportunity for the development of "institutionalized mechanisms of exploitation" (Belasco 1980, 81-82). The palace control of cowries and the elite domination of commercial development in the administrative and economic enclaves provided the final element in the emergence of the dual economy. The capital and commercial centres had developed highly sophisticated and well-organised monetary exchange systems. However, the vassal villages in the empire remained relatively static, with little circulation of either commercial consumer goods or currency forms (cowries or manillas).” [1]

[1]: Sargent, R. A. (1986). From A Redistribution to an Imperial Social Formation: Benin c.1293-1536. Canadian Journal of African Studies / Revue Canadienne Des Études Africaines, 20(3), 402–427: 421. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/AUEZSTBR/collection


434 Karagwe absent Inferred -
The literature suggests that culturally related and geographically adjacent polities in the Great Lakes region did not use paper currency: barter was a common form of exchange, as was the use of tokens (e.g. ivory discs, cowrie shells) and articles (e.g. iron objects). In the case of Rwanda: "Neighbors exchanged goods by barter. Hunters, farmers, and herders exchanged game, leather goods, honey, sorghum, beans, milk, and butter, among other things. Iron objects and hoes above all were preferably exchanged for goats and if possible cattle, but sometimes also for the goods we have just enumerated. Indeed, the hoe was probably already the standard of value as it was in the nineteenth century." [1] In the case of Buganda: "As we have noted, pre-colonial Buganda never developed a purely monetary economy, and even during the later nineteenth century barter was an important method of exchange, existing alongside a cowry currency. Nevertheless, the information we have on nineteenth-century prices suggests that virtually everything had at least a nominal cowry value. Moreover, other currencies existed alongside cowries, and some undoubtedly pre-dated the latter. Roscoe mentions a "small ivory disc" which he terms ’sanga’, ssanga being the Luganda term for either a tusk or ivory in general. This, Roscoe claimed, was one of the earliest forms of money in Buganda; although clearly indigenous and probably much older than the cowry shell, it also had a cowry value. [...] A third pre-cowry currency has already been mentioned, namely the blue bead, and as we have also already noted, examples of beads have been excavated at Ntusi. From such archaeological evidence, it is possible to suggest that beads may be the oldest currency in the region." [2]

[1]: (Vansina 2004: 30) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/5J4MRHUB/collection.

[2]: (Reid 2010: 122, 126-127) Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/collections/GWWIKDDM/items/2H64W34U/collection.


435 Early United Mexican States present Confident -
“As soon as the most turbulent stages of the revolution were over, the economy began to recover. The recovery was preceded by the end of hyperinflation. A return to the gold standard in 1916 provided the basis for rapid stabilization of prices. Two factors were behind the monetary stabilization. Cárdenas and Manns (1987), following Kemmerer (1940), argue that, as notes in circulation progressively lost the functions of money, a reversion of Gresham’s law took place with notes (“bad money”) being replaced by gold and silver (“good money”)… In any case, the government’s decision meant that notes would not function as a means of payment, thus acting as a monetary reform that stabilized prices in terms of the newly circulating coins. Paper money would not circulate again in large amounts until the end of 1931.” [1]

[1]: (Moreno-Brid and Ros 2009: 74-75) Moreno-Brid, Juan Carlos and Ros, Jaime. 2009. Development and Growth in the Mexican Economy: A Historical Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/PZXKGTTV


436 Golden Horde Transitional (Absent -> Present) Confident -
From 1339 onwards the Golden Horde khans received payments from the Yuan dynasty in paper currency (ding). [1]

[1]: Atwood 2004: 206. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/SJXN6MZD.


437 British Empire I Transitional (Absent -> Present) Confident -
The Bank of England began issuing fixed denomination paper currency in the early eighteenth century and partially printed notes from 1725. [1]

[1]: ( Bank of England) Bank of England. ‘History’. https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/about/history. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/PYMZXS4N


438 Anglo-Saxon England II absent Inferred -
No evidence of paper currency referred to in the sources consulted.
439 Anglo-Saxon England I absent Inferred -
No evidence of paper currency referred to in the sources consulted.
440 British Empire IIIIIIIIII present Confident -
The Bank of England had been issuing fixed denomination paper currency and partially printed notes from 1725. [1]

[1]: ( Bank of England. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/PYMZXS4N.


441 Holy Roman Empire - Ottonian-Salian Dynasty absent Confident -
Paper currency was not issued in Europe until 1761 by Austria. [1]

[1]: Wilson 2016: 467. https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/N5M9R9XA


442 Orokaiva - Pre-Colonial absent Confident Expert -
According to SCCS variable 17 ’Money (Media of Exchange) and Credit’, ‘1’ or ’No media of exchange or money’ was present, not ’Domestically used articles as media of exchange’ or ’Tokens of conventional value as media of exchange’ or ’Foreign coinage or paper coinage’, or ’Indigenous coinage or paper currency’. Monetary exchange was introduced by the colonial powers.
443 Qatabanian Commonwealth absent Confident Expert -
-
444 Five Dynasties Period present Confident Expert -
“The guifang was concurrent with another notable Tang monetary innovation: ‘flying cash’ (feiqian 飛錢), introduced during the emperor Xianzong’s (憲􏰀 r. 806–820 CE) reign. Flying cash comprised a public-order mechanism whereby merchants received from the imperial treasury against liquid deposits a paper scrip that could be carried into other provinces easily and cashed in local flying cash depots as the need arose. Guifang and flying cash depots dotted the Tang capital of Chang’an and other urban centers. They became the most visible sign of an increasingly sophisticated credit economy. But, while private-order counting houses were gradually falling from grace, variants of flying cash continued to be used throughout the subsequent Five Dynasties era (907–960 CE), laying the groundwork for the dissemination of the world’s first full-fledged fiduciary paper money during the Northern Song (960–1127 CE).” [1]

[1]: (Horesh 2013: 375) Horesh, N. 2013. ‘CANNOT BE FED ON WHEN STARVING’: AN ANALYSIS OF THE ECONOMIC THOUGHT SURROUNDING CHINA’S EARLIER USE OF PAPER MONEY. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 35(3): 373-395. Seshat URL: https://www.zotero.org/groups/1051264/seshat_databank/items/6PGHSGRX/library


445 Bengal Sultanate absent Confident -
-
446 British East India Company present Confident -
-
447 Qin Empire absent Confident -
-
448 Southern Song present Confident -
-
449 Eastern Zhou absent Inferred -
-
450 Imamate of Oman and Muscat absent Inferred -
-
451 Portuguese Empire - Renaissance Period absent Confident -
-
452 Grand Principality of Moscow, Rurikid Dynasty absent Confident -
-
453 Classic Tana absent Inferred -
-